8 Demand Regimes and Open Economy Neo-Kaleckian Models
8.1 Summary of Kalecki-Steindl model
Wa saw in the previous chapter that the Kalecki-Steindl has strong implications for growth. A decrease in markup and profit share leads to higher growth, real wage and profit rates. Such an economy is known in the literature as wage-led economy.
However, these rather unusual results, compared with all the models seen until now, are the results of the assumptions of the model, which are:
- Flexible capacity rate of utilization
- Markup pricing
- Specification of the investment function: \(g = g_0 + g_r + g_2u\)
- No Government (no taxes, no government spending)
- Closed economy (no foreign trade)
- No savings out of wages (all savings come out of profits)
In this chapter, we will see that some economists came out with different conclusions by relaxing some of the assumptions above. In fact, it will be shown that, by relaxing assumptions 6 and by considering another specification of the investment function, an economy can not only be wage-led, but also profit-led (when demand resulting from investment drives economic growth). A further complexification of the model is to relax assumption 5 and include foreign trade in the model.
8.1.1 Savings out of Wages
8.1.1.1 Similarities with the Early Kaldorian Model
Assuming, as the Kalecki-Steindl model does, that there is no positive savings out of wages is not a realistic assumptions. In effect, savings out of wages can be very low and most of the time lower than savings out of profits, but they still exist. It it thus important to consider how positive savings out of wages can be included in the model, and see how the model changes. It is also important to take savings out of wages into account, because the latter varies a lot accross countries: there are countries in which savings out of wages are relatively higher than other countries (East Asia for instance). Hence, relaxing this assumption is of great interest. But how is it done?
Remember that we already a model which includes positive savings out of wages: the early Kaldorian model (EKM). (Blecker and Setterfield 2019, 182) introduces the following saving function, which is very similar to the EKM saving function:
\[\sigma = S/K = [s_r\pi+s_w(1-\pi)]\frac{u}{a_1}\]
Note that we assume positive savings out of wages, but with a lower propensity than savings out of profits: \(0<s_w<s_r<1\). The rational behind this is that wages recipients have a higher propensity to consumer that profits recipients since the latter have a relatively higher income.
Note that the only difference with the EKM savings function is the fact that \(u\) appears in this alternative Neo-Kaleckian model, whereas is was assumed constant at full capacity in the EKM.
It is important to keep in mind that \(s_r\) and \(s_w\) are the saving propensities out of the types of income received (here profits and wages), they do not refer to saving propensities of workers and capitalists. A worker can receive both wage and profits revenues, and we assume here that workers will save income out of profits more than income out of wages. That means that profits are always saved at a higher propensity than wages.
8.1.1.2 Effects on the model
The main effects of including positive savings out of wages are the following:
The main variables of the model (capacity, profits, investment rates) are now not necessarily inversely related with the profit share. It can be thus possible that the economy is not wage-led.
Whether an economy is wage-led or profit-led depends on the gap between the saving propensity out of profits and wages \((s_r-s_w)\). The higher the gap (the higher \(s_r\) is relatively to \(s_w\)), the more likely is the economy (through demand) to be wage-led, because the gains from increasing consumer demand after redistribution of income towards wages will be large. Remember that when \(s_w =0\), the economy would always be wage-led.
If the gap between \(s_r, s_w\) is small (when \(s_r\) is closed to \(s_w\)), demand is more likely to be profit-led. The logic behind this is that the loss of investment demand after a redistribution of income unfavorable to profits and favorable to wages will outweigh the gain in consumption demand, because the propensity to consume out of wages is relatively low.
The higher the responsiveness of investment to profits (\(g_1\)), the more likely are demand and growth to be profit-led. That means that higher profit share would boost investment so much that the negative effects of reduced consumption out of wages would be surpassed and outweighed.
8.1.2 Modifying the Investment function
8.1.2.1 Flaws of the Kalecki-Steindl Investment function
In the previous chapter, the Kalecki-Steindl investment function was:
\[g=g_0+g_1r+g_2u\]
This specification (was of defining) the investment function as positively related to profit rate of utilization rate was criticized by Marglin and Bhaduri (1991), who argued that the utilization rate is double counted in this specification, imposing an overstated role of demand on investment in the economy. \(u\) is double counted because profit rate can be written as \(r = \pi u/a_1\):
\[g=g_0+g_1\frac{\pi u}{a_1}+g_2u\]
But the double counting of \(u\) is not the only problem. In fact, assuming that \(g_2\) is always positive (meaning that increase in capacity rate will have a positive effect of investment) is also unrealistic, because it implies that when utilization increases and profit share falls simultaneously, firms will always want to invest more1. Marglin and Bhaduri (1991) argued that this was not a reasonable assumption and that \(g_2\) could be either positive or negative.
8.1.2.2 Marglin-Badhuri Investment Function
Marglin and Bhaduri (1991) thus proposed a new investment function combining Kaleckian and Robinsonian elements:
\[g = f[r^e(\pi,u)] = h(\pi,u)\] This modified investment function means that investment depends positively on the capacity rate \(u\) and profit share \(\pi\). This specification assumes that the partial derivatives \(h_\pi\) and \(h_u\) are positive. That means that if \(u\) stays constant and \(\pi\) increase (or conversely), firms will be willing to invest more. \(h_\pi\) is interpreted as the profitability effect of investment (the marginal effect of profit share on investment, with \(u\) fixed).
Using this new investment function, an economy can be profit-led even if we assume that there is not positive savings out of wages \(s_w=0\) and no international trade.
8.2 Summary
To sum up, here’s first an explanation of what is meant by “wage-led” and “profit-led” demand:
Wage-led demand means that aggregate demand \(Y = C+I\) (recall that we assume no government and foreign trade, so aggregate demand ignores \(G\) and \(X-M\)) is driven by private consumption \(C\). In other words, when the wage share increases (and profit share decreases), aggregate demand increases through \(C\) and this effect surpasses the fall of investment \(I\) due to lower profitability. The logic behind wage-led demand is to consider that a redistribution of income towards wages boost private consumption so much that growth, investment, real wage and profit rates increase. Thus, a rise in the wage share boosts the economy through positive effect on demand.
Profit-led demand means that a rise in the profit share boosts investment so much that this effect offsets and even surpasses the fall in private consumption due to a fall in the wage share. Firms are very responsive to the increase in their profit share and are thus willing to invest a lot.
8.3 Open Economy Neo-Kaleckian Model
How would the neo-Kaleckian model change is the assumption of no foreign trade is relaxed? So that aggregate demand now includes \(X-M\), the external balance (exports minus imports) in \(Y = C+I+(X-M)\).
Taking foreign trade into account changes how labor costs, or rising real wage/wage share can affect aggregate demand and output. A rise in unit labor costs \(Wa_0=WL/Y\) in an economy (“home economy”) can potentially lead to a rise in the price of exported goods, for instance if unit labor cost rise in a firm which exports a lot of goods. This rise in the price of exports implies a loss of competitiveness: demand for the exported goods can decrease in the price increase too much relatively with other exporting countries. Home products thus loose competitiveness, and this can have an negative impact on aggregate demand which surpasses the positive impact due to the rise of consumer demand (due to rise in wages). A redistribution of income favorable to wages can, even if the domestic economy is wage-led, lead to a contraction of aggregate demand and output.
8.3.1 New Markup Pricing Equation
Relaxing the assumption of no foreign trade also affects how markup pricing is defined. Remember from last chapter that the markup pricing equation was:
\[P = (1+\tau)Wa_0\]
This equation can be rewritten to write markup rate \(1+\tau\) as a function of price and unit labor cost:
\[1+\tau=\frac{P}{Wa_0}\]
(Blecker and Setterfield 2019, 190) then rewrite the right part of this equation as follows:
\[1+\tau=\mu\left(\frac{EP_f}{P}\right)^\eta\]
With \(\mu>1\) the target or desired markup rate of firms, \(P_f\) the foreign price level, \(P\) home price level, \(E\) nominal exchange rate and \(\eta\) the elasticity of the price–cost margin with respect to the real exchange rate.
This equation basically tells that when real exchange rate rises \(\nearrow \left(\frac{EP_f}{P}\right)\), meaning that home goods and services become relatively cheaper (foreign goods become more expensive, there is a real depreciation of home currency, foreign currencies become more expensive), firms will respond by raising their markup to take advantage of increasing competitiveness (make more revenues for each sale).
Conversely, if home products become relatively more expensive (the real exchange rate appreciate, \(\searrow \left(\frac{EP_f}{P}\right)\)), firms will decrease their markup to try to keep competitiveness (keep selling goods).
By replacing \(P\) in the denominator of the equation above by \((1+\tau)Wa_0\), leads to:
\[1+\tau=\mu^{\frac{1}{1+\eta}}\left(\frac{EP_f}{Wa_0}\right)^{\frac{\eta}{1+\eta}}\]
\(\frac{EP_f}{Wa_0}\) is the ratio of foreign price to domestic unit labor cost (how much labor costs for each unit of output). This ratio is a measure of firms’ international competitiveness in terms of unit labor costs. Thus, international trade changes the model by showing a negative impact of unit labor costs on markup \(\tau\).
8.3.3 Modelling the Trade Balance
The next step is to model net exports \((X-M)\). The trade balance is considered a positive function of the real exchange rate \(\frac{EP_f}{P}\) and negatively related to the ratio of capacity utilization on the capital-output ratio \(\frac{u}{a_1}\):
\[b=b\left(\frac{EP_f}{P}_{(+)}, \frac{u}{a_1}_{(-)}\right)\]
Net exports are positively related with the real exchange rate, because an increase of the latter is synonym of real depreciation and, assuming that the Marshall-Lerner condition is satisfied2, real depreciation ameliorates the trade balance by increasing exports.
Trade balance \(b\) in inversely related to \(u/a_1\) because the increase in the latter is associated with rising demand for imports relative to capital.
8.3.4 New Investment Function
Regarding the investment function, the latter becomes:
\[g=h_0+h_1(\pi-\pi_f)+h_2\frac{u}{a_1}\]
With \(h_1,h_2>0\). What changes is that investment now depends positively on the difference between the domestic profit share and the foreign profit share \((\pi-\pi_f)\). The reason is that once we consider competition with foreign countries, the profit share of the domestic country must be greater than profit share in foreign countries. Otherwise, capital would simply move abroad (firms would not invest in the home economy if profits are higher in other parts of the world). \((\pi-\pi_f)\) can be interpreted as a difference in profitability between the domestic economy and the rest of the world.
8.3.5 New Equilibrium Condition
Now that we are considering trade balance, domestic savings \(\sigma\) are not only equal to domestic investment \(g\), but also equal to the trade balance \(b\):
\[\sigma=g+b\]
The variables above could be replaced by their respective definitions, but since it would be tedious, I will simply conclude by summarizing the intuitions of how the main variables of interest interact between them.
8.3.6 Impacts of variations in \(z\) and \(\mu\)
Since the two exogenous variables of this model are the target markup for firms \(\mu\) and the international competitiveness to labor costs ratio \(z = \frac{EP_f}{Wa_0}\), we have to see how their variation impact the other variables of the model to see what are the main results and conclusions of the model.
8.3.6.1 Increase in markup \(\mu\)
An increase in target markup for firms (for instance after reduced competition) increases (domestic) profit share, but decreases international competitiveness since an increase in target markups increases domestic prices.
A rise in markup \(\mu\) makes home products more expensive and thus reduces net exports while at the same time increasing the profit share \(\pi\) and reducing the equilibrium rate of capacity, making the economy more likely to be wage-led.
\(\nearrow{\mu} \Rightarrow \searrow{b} \Rightarrow \searrow{u}, \nearrow \pi\)
8.3.7 Open Economy neo-Kaleckian Model and Currency Depreciation
This neo-Kaleckian open economy model also has strong implication for foreign trade policy (currency depreciation).
A depreciation makes \(z\) rise. If the domestic economy shows profit-led response to such a shock (meaning that exports increase a lot and outweigh the loss in consumption demand from decreased purchasing power of households), the depreciation is expansionary.
On the other hand, if the economy shows a wage-led response, the depreciation will not be expansionary. The reason is that depreciation reduces domestic purchasing power of households and if domestic demand is strongly wage-led, depreciation will not rise exports enough to compensate the loss in domestic consumer demand and will have negative effects on growth.
Finally, a depreciation, rise in \(z\), will always rise profit share and thus make the distribution of income more unequal. In addition, if the economy has wage-led demand, the depreciation is likely to be contractionary.
Here’s the complete explanation: \(g_2\) is the effect of \(u\) on investment with \(r\) fixed. Since \(r = \frac{\pi u}{a_1}\), assuming \(g_2>0\) implies that when \(u\) rises, \(r\) stays constant because profit share \(\pi\) falls in the exact same proportion.↩︎
The Marshall-Lerner condition refers to the conditions that leads real depreciation to improve net exports (trade balance). A depreciation has basically two effects. On the one hand, it makes home products relatively cheaper in the world market and thus increases exports of domestic products. On the other hand, real depreciation also makes imported goods dearer (for the same quantity of imports). The effect of depreciation on exported quantities is called “volume effect” and the effect on imported price “value effect”. For the depreciation to have a positive impact on net exports, the volume effect has to outweigh the value effect. In other words, the increase in exports needs to surpass the increase of the value of imported goods and services.↩︎